Behrens regional economics a new economic geography, Naukowe, Geografia ekonomiczna
[ Pobierz całość w formacie PDF ]
Regional Science and Urban Economics 37 (2007) 457
–
465
www.elsevier.com/locate/regec
Regional economics: A new economic
geography perspective
☆
⁎
Kristian Behrens
a
, Jacques-François Thisse
a,b,c,
a
CORE, Université Catholique de Louvain, Belgium
b
CERAS, Ecole Nationale des Ponts et Chaussées, France
c
CEPR, United Kingdom
Received 5 August 2006; accepted 19 October 2006
Available online 12 April 2007
Abstract
We show that the concepts and tools developed in new economic geography may be used to revisit several
problems in regional economics. In particular, we want to stress the following two points: (i) what do we mean
by a region and (ii) what kind of interactions between regions do we want to study and how to model them? We
conclude by discussing a few open problems that should be explored in more detail for regional economics to
become a richer body of knowledge.
© 2007 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
JEL classification: R1
Keywords: Regions; Regional economics; New economic geography
1. Introduction
This journal has been launched in 1972 under the title Regional and Urban Economics, which
is almost the name of the JEL-classification entry R. The first point we wish to make is that, by the
time this journal was launched, urban economics was already a well-established field drawing on
new concepts and tools. By contrast, the scientific status of regional economics was less clear in
☆
We thank a referee, Richard Arnott, Wilfried Koch and Giordano Mion for helpful comments and suggestions. Kristian
Behrens gratefully acknowledges financial support from the European Commission under the Marie Curie Fellowship
MEIF-CT-2005-024266.
⁎
Corresponding author. CERAS, Ecole Nationale des Ponts et Chaussées, France.
E-mail addresses:
(K. Behrens),
(J.-F. Thisse).
0166-0462/$ - see front matter © 2007 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
doi:
458
K. Behrens, J.-F. Thisse / Regional Science and Urban Economics 37 (2007) 457
–
465
that regional concepts, models and techniques were too often a mere extension of those used at the
national level, with an additional index identifying the different regions (see, e.g., interregional
input
Domar model of regional growth).
1
The Samuelsonian
emphasis put on trade theory also acted as an impediment to the further development of regional
economics, the trade of goods being viewed as a substitute to the mobility of factors. Today,
thanks to the surge of new economic geography (in short, NEG), it is time to re-think regional
economics. This is what we wish to do in this note.
It is worth stressing from the outset that, in order to talk even halfway sensibly about regional
economics, it is necessary to tackle the following two questions: (i) what do we mean by a region;
and (ii) what kind of interactions between regions do we want to study and how to model them?
Regarding the first question, we find it crucial to develop a better understanding of how the
spatial scale of the analysis matters for the economic results. Too often, economists use
interchangeably different, yet equally unclear, words such as locations, regions or places without
being aware that they often correspond to different spatial units. In doing so, they run the risk of
drawing implications that are valid at a certain level of spatial aggregation but not at another.
2
Furthermore, using vague definitions of the spatial unit of analysis reduces the scientific contents
of the theory in the Popperian sense, as the empirical results can always be contested in light of the
theory on the sole basis that variables are not measured at the appropriate spatial scale.
As to the second question, regardless of what is meant by a region, the concept is useful if and
only if a region is part of a broader network through which various types of interactions occur.
Without taking this aspect into account, one may wonder what the difference between regional
economics and the macroeconomics of a closed economy would be. When there is a single region,
the economy is a-spatial and there is nothing interesting to be said in terms of spatial analysis.
Hence, any meaningful discussion of regional issues requires at least two regions in which
economic decisions are made. Furthermore, if we do not want the analysis to be confined to trade
theory, we must also account explicitly for the mobility of agents
–
output matrices or the Harrod
–
as
well as for the existence of transport costs, which are the two main ingredients of location theory.
In the first two sections, we briefly review what we know and do not know about those two
questions. We conclude in Section 4 by discussing a few open problems that should be explored in
more detail for regional economics to reach the level of generality one expects for such an
important field.
–
firms and/or consumers
–
2. What is a region?
Since the early days of regional economics, there have been many definitions for and approaches
to the concept of a region,
Lösch (1938)
being probably the most stimulating contribution. In its
broadest sense, the term
is used to describe a bundle of places such that any two places
belonging to the same region are, in a way or another, similar. Yet, the multiplicity of definitions
reflects the fact that the concept of similarity to be used does not suggest itself. This difficulty may be
formalized in a very rigorous, but largely unnoticed, way.
Observe first that a set of regions always involves a partition of some geographical space that
contains a
“
region
”
“
large
”
number of places
—
a place being the elementary spatial unit. Keeping this in
1
A noticeable exception is the work of Takayama and Judge (1971), which has led to a large body of extensions and
real-world applications.
2
For example,
Rosenthal and Strange (2001)
show that the nature of agglomeration forces differs depending on the
spatial scale of the analysis (zipcode, county level, state level).
K. Behrens, J.-F. Thisse / Regional Science and Urban Economics 37 (2007) 457
–
465
459
mind, a well-known result in set theory is that there is a one-to-one correspondence between the
family of partitions in a set and the family of equivalence relations of the same set (
Halmos, 1965
).
Recall that an equivalence relation in a set is a reflexive, symmetric and transitive relation.
Intuitively, one may think of an equivalence relation as a generalization of the concept of equality
to that of similarity: (i) an object is always similar to itself (reflexivity); (ii) if one object is similar to
another, the latter is similar to the former (symmetry); and (iii) two objects similar to a third one are
themselves similar (transitivity).
Accordingly, using a particular regional system amounts to working with a special equivalence
relation defined on the space of reference. This result has two important implications: (i) any place
belongs to a single region and (ii) two places belonging to the same region are considered as being
identical from the standpoint of the equivalence relation, whereas two places belonging to two distinct
regions are not. It is now easy to understand why there is no general agreement on what a region should
be: the number of equivalence relations that can be defined in a space is
. Thus, depending on
the point of view selected by the analyst, the regional system, whence the shape and number of
regions, may vary. Consequently, a given area cannot be considered as a region per se. Whether or not
it is part of a regional system ultimately depends on the equivalence relation that is being used.
This difficulty should not come as a surprise as defining a regional system bears some
resemblance with the problem of aggregation in economic theory. In this respect, it is well known
how poorly representative the so-called
“
huge
”
“
representative consumer
”
may be (
Kirman, 1992
).
Likewise, the word
is still in search of a well-defined theoretical meaning (
Triffin,
1940
). Grouping locations within the same spatial entity, called a region, gives rise to similar
difficulties. It is, therefore, probably hopeless to give a clear and precise answer to our first
question, which is essentially an empirical one. When we talk about a region, we must be happy
with the same theoretical vagueness that we encounter when using the concept of industry. Note
that both involve some
“
industry
”
level of aggregation between the macro and the micro.
It should be clear from the foregoing discussion that the main challenge in defining a regional
system lies more in the empirical application one has in mind. From a purely empirical point of
view, the concept of region one retains is often intrinsically linked to the availability of data.
Hence, the question of the spatial scale of analysis, though already problematic in theory,
becomes even more dramatic in applied research. However, such a difficulty does not dispense the
analyst from seeking meaningful empirical solutions (see, e.g.
Magrini, 2004; McMillen and
Smith, 2003
). On the one hand, the question of the size of regions no longer matters because it is
often dictated by administrative classifications (e.g., the NUTS regional classification of the EU).
On the other hand, one is tempted to twist theory so that it fits into the available statistical
classifications. One additional problem is that, due to the nature of the data available, space must
often be represented by a discrete set of points. Yet, when there are too many points, aggregation
becomes necessary and gives rise to another problem, known as the MAUP (Movable Areal Unit
Problem).
3
Some new techniques should alleviate the MAUP problem. In particular, the use of
geographical information systems and the increasing availability of micro-spatial data should
allow for less reliance on arbitrarily determined regional boundaries.
4
“
intermediate
”
3
Economists and geographers do not seem to be aware that mathematicians have extensively studied the possible errors
that may emerge from the aggregation of data. In this perspective,
Francis et al. (2007)
consider and compare various
aggregation error measures, identify some effective (and some ineffective) aggregation error measures, and discuss some
open research areas.
4
For example,
Duranton and Overman (2005)
start from a continuous space approach to determine the degree of spatial
concentration of various industrial sectors, whereas
Mori et al. (2005)
propose an index of industrial location that can be
decomposed into components representing localization at various levels of spatial aggregation.
460
K. Behrens, J.-F. Thisse / Regional Science and Urban Economics 37 (2007) 457
–
465
3. The relationship between regional economics and NEG
The idea of spatial interaction is central to regional economics. Broadly defined, spatial
interaction refers to a wide array of flows subject to various types of spatial frictions, such as
traded goods, migrations, capital movements, interregional grants, remittances, and the
interregional transmission of knowledge and business cycle effects. So far, the bulk of NEG
has been restricted to the movements of goods and of some agents only.
As argued in the foregoing section, defining clearly and delineating precisely a region appears
to be a difficult, not to say impossible, task. Keeping this in mind, we assume from now on that
regions may be viewed as units where economic activity takes place. In light of this (vague)
definition, it becomes crucial for the analysis to account for the fact that where things happen is
endogenously determined in a regional system. In this respect, traditional regional economics
often fails to grasp such an issue by taking the location of production factors as given, very much
as in trade theory.
How can (or should) a regional system be formally represented is still a matter of debate.
Firstly, one may consider that there is a discrete set of regions. Alternatively, one may assume that
there is a continuum of regions. Although the second approach may seem more appropriate when
we want to work at a very disaggregate spatial level, it seems natural to think of a regional system
as being formed by a finite set of regions. Furthermore, NEG shows that even when location
spaces are continuous, economic activity usually clusters into a few places.
5
This leads us to
believe that the operationally feasible and theoretically desirable representation of a regional
system is in terms of a graph. Note that this is the approach that has been chosen for a long time in
location theory (
Beckmann and Thisse, 1986
). Indeed, graphs offer a natural representation of
finite systems of agents/nodes which interact with each other through links. It also fits well the
intermediate spatial scale considered in regional economics.
In a spatial economy with a finite number of regions, we know from Starrett's Spatial
Impossibility Theorem that the competitive market mechanism breaks down when the mobility of
firms and/or households is combined with the transport costs of goods between regions. Hence,
unless strong spatial heterogeneities are assumed to be given a priori, the question of where
economic activity occurs and why cannot be readily addressed within the competitive framework.
As argued by
Krugman (1995)
, this probably explains why spatial economic issues have been for
so long at the periphery of mainstream economics. Note, in passing, that a major implication of
the Spatial Impossibility Theorem is that some forms of imperfect competition are likely to be
necessary to handle regional issues. It is no surprise, therefore, that the surge of NEG took place a
few years after the revival of monopolistic competition and industrial organization, from which
NEG borrows many ideas and concepts.
Since the pioneering work of
Krugman (1991)
, NEG has become a fast-growing field (
Fujita
et al., 1999; Baldwin et al., 2003; Ottaviano and Thisse, 2004
). It provides a full-fledged general
equilibrium approach with strong microeconomic underpinnings in which regional disparities
may or may not emerge endogenously, depending on the values of some structural parameters. In
this respect, it seems fair to say that NEG is the first successful attempt made to explain why
5
To be sure, the initial strategy used in NEG was in terms of two regions. However, later developments have shown
that the basic ideas remain applicable to continuous space models (see, e.g.
Fujita et al., 1999; Picard and Tabuchi, 2003
).
In this context, a precise definition of a region is not really needed since regions appear endogenously as clusters of
activities. In such a context, regions become even more of a relative concept because they are subject to changes in the
economic environment.
K. Behrens, J.-F. Thisse / Regional Science and Urban Economics 37 (2007) 457
–
465
461
a priori similar regions do not experience the same level of economic development. When
compared to earlier attempts made in regional economics, one appealing feature of NEG is that it
has very strong connections with several branches of modern economics, including industrial
organization and urban economics, but also with the new theories of growth and development. In
particular, NEG and endogenous growth theory share the same framework, using monopolistic
competition, increasing returns and spillovers. This suggests the existence of a high potential for
cross-fertilization, which is being explored in recent contributions (
Baldwin and Martin, 2004
).
Another striking aspect of NEG is the very large number of empirical investigations it has
triggered (
Head and Mayer, 2004
). However, if empirical papers deal with many regions (and
sectors), theory has focused almost exclusively on two regions (and sectors). Although such simple
settings have proven to be valuable to our understanding of spatial phenomena, they offer in
general a fairly poor basis for deriving testable predictions (
Behrens et al., 2005a
). In addition, it is
far from being clear that we can extrapolate the predictions and results derived from two-region
models to a multi-regional system. Quite the opposite: the answer is probably no although this is
not really recognized by the profession. Note that such
are reminiscent of
fairly old debates in trade theory. As concisely emphasized by
Deardorff (1984, p.468)
, the
Heckscher
“
dimensionality issues
”
is derived from a model of only two of each of goods, countries, and
factors of production. It is unclear what the theorem says should be true in the real world where
there are many of all three
–
Ohlin theorem
“
papers that claim to
present tests of the hypothesis have used intuitive but inappropriate generalizations of the
two× two model to deal with a multidimensional reality
”
. This inevitably affects applied work, since most
“
(
Bowen et al., 1987
, p.791). The
dimensionality issue is likely to be part of the explanation for the
”
provided by
the numerous attempts made to test the theoretical predictions of NEG (
Head and Mayer, 2004
).
A last remark is in order. NEG models typically rest on very specific models of monopolistic
competition, mainly the one by Dixit and Stiglitz. Therefore, such models lack the level of
generality that characterizes standard general equilibrium theory. Hence, it is fair to say that NEG
models have so far the scientific status of examples. We are fully aware of the many conceptual
and technical difficulties encountered in building general equilibrium models with imperfect
competition and increasing returns, so that working with a general model is probably out of reach.
Yet, for NEG and regional economics to achieve the status of economic theories, it is necessary,
we believe, to explore alternative formulations of monopolistic competition, and to check whether
its main conclusions remain valid within such frameworks.
6
“
moderate support
”
4. From two to many regions
In many scientific fields, the passage from one to two dimensions raises fundamental
conceptual difficulties. In NEG, it is the apparently innocuous passage from two to three regions.
The reason for this is that when there are just two regions, there is only one way in which these
regions can interact, namely directly; whereas with three regions, there are two ways in which
these regions can interact, namely directly and indirectly. In other words, in multi-regional
systems the so-called
“
three-ness effect
”
enters the picture and introduces complex feedbacks into
6
Ottaviano et al. (2002)
revisit the core
–
periphery model within an alternative monopolistic competition model
featuring price competition effects and quasi-linear preferences. They show that the main conclusions of NEG are robust
with respect to these changes.
Behrens and Murata (in press)
propose an alternative framework of monopolistic
competition with both price competition and income effects. Its future application to NEG may constitute another step in
the direction of exploring the robustness of this theory.
[ Pobierz całość w formacie PDF ]